Not a member of Pastebin yet?
Sign Up,
it unlocks many cool features!
- Scarcely a day goes by on these here internets without some goddamn 14 year old telling you
- that you don't understand economics. Well I'm here to say that these 14 year olds, are wrong.
- But this video is about so much more than just arguing with children. The problem is that many
- people in positions of power and influence, as well as parts of the economics profession,
- share the view that 'economics 101' is the reason we can't improve the world, especially for poor people.
- In some cases this seems like a genuine intellectual commitment by people who sincerely
- believe economic theory helps us make sense of the world, but that it just leads us to unpalatable
- conclusions. In a recent YouTube documentary about
- the economist Thomas Sowell which mysteriously
- appeared in everyone's recommendations, there
- was a famous quote from the man himself
- In other cases the same argument can seem like an
- ideological commitment underpinned by nothing but
- empty sociopathic tendencies. Not too long ago
- noted personality vacuum Abby Shapiro tweeted that
- Let's leave aside the question of what education Abby has actually had in economics.
- Because it's not just for the extremely online
- among us that economics makes its influence felt.
- You can even see it pretty often in popular
- culture: "I spend money to make money, economics
- 101 dude" "What have we here? Oh, economics! Very
- very interesting" "I'm confused" "It's a question of
- economics" "I'm sorry boys, you just don't understand
- economics" "Simple economics" The reality is that
- economics is just a set of theories which may or
- may not hold in the real world and over the past
- few decades it has been shown time and time again
- that the standard econ 101 story is misleading at
- best and flatly contradicted by the evidence at
- worst. Over the course of this video, I want to
- detail both the theory and the evidence in this
- debate, with some help from Mexie, who kindly agreed
- to offer her views. And before loads of tedious
- economists pop up in my mentions claiming that
- I'm strawmanning them or that I should learn
- economics before I unlearn it I'd like to
- say that yes, the content of actual economics
- 101 classes has changed recently. This video
- is largely about how a selectively interpreted
- version of this has been used in political debate
- on issues spanning from minimum wages to rent
- control to taxes and spending. Having said that,
- I do think these ideas still exert something of a
- grip on the profession of economics, as we'll see.
- In the Thomas Sowell documentary they single out the
- minimum wage as an example of how economics shows
- you the true impact of well-intended policies. "One
- of my biggest concerns was about minimum wages. At
- first I thought this is good because all these
- people are poor and they'll get a little higher
- income and so that'll be helpful and then as I
- studied economics I began to say well there's a
- downside, they may lose their jobs completely so
- there's that." This reasoning is based on
- standard demand-supply analysis which epitomises
- the core of economics 101. When somebody tells
- you to go and learn economics chances are this is
- what they have in mind, so let's do what they say
- and learn about it. Demand and supply is used to
- represent a variety of markets, but the one we've
- got here is the labour market. It shows how - in
- theory - the market for labor will settle at a given
- level of wages, on the y-axis, and employment, on the
- x-axis. It can also show the effects of the minimum
- wage on these quantities, but we don't want to get
- ahead of ourselves so let's take demand and supply
- one at a time. The demand for labour depicts
- the willingness of business to employ workers
- in the form of a relationship between wages and
- employment. If the wage is high, say at the level W1,
- businesses will not find it profitable to employ
- many workers. On the graph if you travel right
- from W1 until you hit the demand curve and then go
- down until you hit the x-axis you will get to E1 -
- the corresponding level of employment at this
- wage. On the other hand, if the wage is lower at
- W2 then businesses will employ more workers and
- employment will be at E2. Generally speaking, the
- lower the wage the more workers businesses
- will want. The demand curve slopes downwards,
- an expression you may well have heard before. So
- what about the other side of the equation - supply?
- Well here we are looking at the amount of
- labour workers are willing to supply for a wage.
- This is a strange way of putting it that
- might not come naturally to most people,
- but the important thing to know is that if the
- wage is higher more people will want to work.
- Which makes some sense, I guess. So if the wage
- is high at W1, employment will be high at E3.
- If the wage is lower at W2, employment will be low
- at E4. The supply curve slopes upwards. I hope
- you're ready because we're about to put the two
- curves together. Demand curves depict the number of
- workers businesses are willing to employ at a given
- wage. Supply curves depict the amount workers
- are willing to work at a given wage. Where these
- cross over, the decisions of the businesses balance
- with the decisions of the workers and we get the
- outcome of wages W-star and employment E-star: what
- economists call an equilibrium. "You have a product,
- they have no means of distribution. They have
- demand, they- they don't have any product. That's
- that's market equilibrium: yin and yang, ebony and ivory.
- Tell me what the [ __ ] problem is." So how does
- our minimum wage affect this happy depiction of
- the labor market? The minimum wage is represented
- by this god-awful ugly line MW that's interfering
- with our precious market. It might seem odd that
- with the name 'minimum' wage the line is high up on
- the diagram. (Maybe it's just me that finds that
- odd). But remember that the point of a minimum
- wage is to increase wages above the level they're
- currently at, so it has to be higher than where the
- curves cross over to have any effect. Now how do we
- work out the effects of this minimum on employment?
- Well, no matter what the market wage is stuck
- at MW so we need to ask where this crosses the
- demand curve - how much labour businesses will hire
- at MW - and also where it crosses the supply curve -
- how much workers will want to work at MW. At the
- minimum wage, businesses will only want to employ
- the number of workers E-MW. More will want to work
- because MW crosses the supply curve much further
- to the right, at a higher level of employment E-star-S. But businesses are not willing to employ so
- many workers at such a high wage, therefore the
- employment level E-MW will be the one that is
- realised. Notice that this is also lower than
- the previous equilibrium E-star. The minimum
- wage has reduced employment! [ __ ] what are we
- going to do? It is important to remember that
- this is a prediction of the model, not some kind of
- logical necessity. And I actually don't think most
- non-economists are aware of quite how convincing
- the empirical evidence against standard theory
- has been on this issue. For example, in a video on
- the minimum wage the YouTuber Vaush makes some
- good points about why the minimum wage could be
- a positive thing and raises some valid questions
- about a well-known Congressional Budget Office
- study predicting that it would lead to job losses.
- "How many of these are like real [ __ ] 40-hour
- week proper jobs. I'd be willing to bet very few of
- them. Most of these are cuck jobs and the loss of
- these jobs could actually be a good thing because
- it would mean the people who were otherwise
- taking them can now afford to live off of only
- one job instead of having to take two or three." But we can add a bit to what Vaush says- um, sorry,
- scratch that. In a recent video on the minimum
- wage 'manlet' Vaush shows how little he knows
- about anything by failing to bring up well-known
- studies on the minimum wage and accepting the
- central finding of the CBO study like a cuck, even
- though it's definitely false. To see why Vaush is
- so hopelessly destroyed by facts and logic, we're
- going to take a deep dive into the literature on
- the minimum wage. Doing so will teach us not just
- about why minimum wages are good, but also about
- the kind of empirical studies that have shown this,
- as well as the limitations of economics 101 itself.
- Newly elected U.S. President Joe Biden promised
- to introduce a 15 Federal minimum wage once
- elected, which sparked a renewed debate over the
- pros and cons of the policy. As I write this the
- proposal has been voted down in the Senate, which
- is extremely disappointing but shows that econ101-ism
- is alive and kicking, I suppose. Since the
- dawn of time the U.S.A.'s federal minimum wage has
- stagnated or even fallen. As you can see here, in
- the early 80s it was around three dollars an hour
- and despite steady rises in the headline value
- it has only kept pace with inflation since then -
- barely changing in real terms. The U.S.A. lags behind
- other rich countries and even many poorer ones in
- its low minimum wage. As this table shows, the ratio
- of minimum to median wages is only 33 percent for
- the U.S. compared to 54 for my own country of the
- U.K. or 69 for Chile and Costa Rica. The debate is
- relevant to a broad range of countries: in the
- U.K. we have had the living wage campaign, which
- used social pressure to force companies to
- increase their wages and eventually made its
- way into policy for those aged 25 and over. There
- is also the global living wage initiative which....
- campaigns for a global living wage. So what does
- the evidence say on minimum wage increases and
- employment? Before we go into this I want
- to define a crucial term: the elasticity.
- "Yo, you know what we got here? We got an elastic
- product! You know what that means? That means
- when people can go elsewhere and get they printin' and copyin' done they're going to do it! You
- acting like we got an inelastic product and we
- don't!" In economics, this means the percentage
- change in one thing because of a percentage
- change in another thing. Stringer was talking about
- the change in demand owing to the change in the
- price of their product, but here we will mostly be
- talking about the change in employment owing to a
- change in the minimum wage. So an elasticity of -1
- means that if the minimum wage increases by
- one percent employment will fall by one percent.
- An elasticity of minus 0.1 means that if
- the minimum wage increases by one percent,
- employment will fall by 0.1 percent. You can
- see that the former would be hugely problematic
- while the latter could easily be considered a
- price worth paying for higher wages. For a long
- time, economists accepted that the minimum wage
- would be bad for employment based on the supply
- and demand theory we've seen, as well as using what
- are now seen as relatively crude tests that today
- are not considered credible even by opponents
- of the minimum wage. Except for the people in
- the Thomas Sowell documentary, evidently. Beginning
- with a famous paper by David Card and Alan Krueger
- in 1994, a wave of studies sometimes dubbed the
- 'New Minimum Wage Research' have used careful
- empirical techniques to investigate the elasticity
- of employment with respect to minimum wage changes.
- Card and Krueger looked at the effect of a minimum
- wage change using two adjacent U.S. states: New
- Jersey and Pennsylvania. In 1992 New Jersey
- increased its minimum wage, while Pennsylvania
- did not. This is a kind of 'natural experiment' -
- when the policy applied to one area is not
- applied to a similar area, and comparisons between
- the two approximate the ideal of a lab experiment.
- The argument goes that if two areas differ only
- in the policy - in this case, the minimum wage -
- any difference in outcomes between them - in this
- case, employment - can be attributed to that policy.
- Since the U.S. has many state-level policies it is
- fertile ground for these natural experiments.
- Card and Krueger phoned fast food restaurants,
- which employ a lot of minimum wage workers,
- both before and after the change. "Can I help
- you sir? My god you're greasy". What they
- found was that far from reducing employment
- in New Jersey, the minimum wage may actually
- have increased it. That's right: for some of
- their results, the elasticity was positive.
- The study made quite an impact. Reid Garfield,
- Senior Economist of the Joint Economic Committee,
- commented in 1996:
- Since this, thousands of papers have been written in the USA and elsewhere on the employment effects of the minimum wage. One of the most pertinent critiques
- of Card and Krueger was how narrow their study
- was: a single change in fast food restaurants
- in two relatively small U.S. states should not
- be generalized to minimum wages everywhere. More
- recently, the frontier of minimum wage research
- has been led by people like Arin Dube and his
- co-authors. They have mostly followed in Card and Krueger's footsteps by taking advantage of natural
- experiments, but have substantially broadened the
- number of states they include as well as the time
- frame of the studies and the depth they go into
- estimating the effects. For example, in a 2010
- paper Dube, Lester and Reich found no employment
- effects of the minimum wage using adjacent pairs
- of states. That's Card and Krueger times by hundreds! "My god. That's - I don't even know what that is!"
- "Nobody does." A 2019 paper by Cengiz, Dube, Lindner and Zipperer estimated the effect of minimum wages
- on the entire distribution of jobs using 138
- different minimum wage changes in the U.S.A.
- The x-axis here shows the part of the wage
- distribution we're in relative to the minimum. 'Two'
- means it's two dollars higher than the new minimum
- wage. The y-axis shows the effect on employment at
- a given part of the wage distribution. Just below
- the minimum wage - zero on the x-axis - a substantial
- number of jobs disappear, as shown by the negative
- blue bar. Which makes sense as it's now illegal
- to employ people at that wage. But this is offset
- entirely by the appearance of jobs at or above the
- new minimum wage, as shown by the positive blue
- bar to its right. There are no effects anywhere
- else in the distribution, so this gain in wages for
- low income workers is not offset by other workers
- losing out. The same paper looks at these effects
- over the long term and it shows that the new jobs
- which appear do not disappear after a few years. I favour this type of natural experiment approach.
- It's transparent, and the core of close comparison
- between pairs of real regions keeps the method
- grounded in empirical reality - instead of
- blinding us with complex statistical methods.
- But I should say that it's not the case that
- every study has found no effect like this. There
- are dissenters within this literature, specifically
- economists like David Neumark and his co-authors.
- The details of this debate are too heavy for
- this video, so maybe I'll leave a comment with
- my thoughts if you'd like, along with their papers
- in the references. Overall, though, most systematic
- meta-analyses find a small but statistically
- significant negative elasticity of employment
- with respect to minimum wage changes. Having said
- that, these studies also show evidence that there
- is a bias towards publishing negative estimates. Why that's the case I'll leave you to figure out.
- So how does one make sense of such a vast and
- tricky literature? Well....not the way the CBO does it.
- To give you some background, the Congressional
- Budget Office is an official but non-partisan
- entity in the USA which produces research on
- important policy topics. Their recent report
- claimed that raising the minimum wage to 15 would
- lead to 1.4 million job losses, a pretty concerning
- figure. Where did they get their estimates from? Vaush said that he'd have to get a textbook out
- to understand this debate. I'd hate to be the
- reason that anyone had to read an econometrics
- textbook, so let's save him from having to do so...
- Uh oh, too late brah! The first thing to say is that
- this report was kind of opaque, even for someone
- who is used to reading this type of thing. It's
- full of phrases like "CBO concluded" and "In CBO's
- estimation" often with little to no explanation.
- They select 11 studies from the literature, but
- why these 11 were chosen is not explained. The
- CBO then computes the effect of minimum wages on
- employment from an average of the 11 studies but
- they increase the magnitude of the actual average
- because of a really weird thing they do where they
- randomly drop some of the studies they use and
- recalculate the average with those studies missing.
- I don't know why this method is chosen or how it
- really works because again it isn't explained. "It's
- garbage." Dube himself has commented to similar
- effect, though in more measured academic terms.
- He says the CBO overemphasises the negative
- estimates in what we already know is a literature
- biased towards finding negative estimates. He points
- out that more recent, better quality research has
- found employment elasticities of the minimum wage
- closer to zero. As an alternative he suggested his
- own 2009 review for the U.K. Treasury. This only
- includes studies which estimated the effect on
- employment for the same workers whose wages are
- increased by the minimum wage, which gives a clear
- picture of the trade-offs faced by the workers
- actually affected by the policy. This is known as
- the 'Own Wage Elasticity'. Along the y-axis is the
- study. The dots represent the estimated effect
- size for that study, with the bars either side of
- the dots representing the uncertainty surrounding
- that estimate. Dube concludes that based on this
- review ,the average elasticity is minus 0.04,
- meaning that a 25% increase in average wages for a
- group affected by the minimum wage should reduce
- employment by one percent for that group. There's
- a lot of debate over whether $15 an hour is enough
- and Dube also comments on how high the minimum
- wage could be:
- Now, to return to demand and supply. Strictly speaking this evidence alone doesn't contradict the supply and demand model; it
- could just imply that the curves have a specific
- shape - albeit an unlikely one that contradicts
- other evidence, I'll provide a reference for that
- below - but here's my bottom line. When effect sizes
- are this small and uncertain, it's suggestive of
- something that's just not that interesting, whether
- theoretically or politically. As the economist
- Thomas Leonard pointed out, this whole debate does
- prompt the question "what evidence would convince
- you that your theory is refuted?" Let me illustrate
- this with one more recent study. This shows a bunch
- of different elasticities for 16 to 19 year olds,
- the group most likely to be affected by the policy. As you can see, in most cases the blue horizontal
- lines cross zero, which is given by the red
- vertical line, indicating that the effects
- estimated are not statistically distinguishable
- from none at all. As a contrast consider a more
- straightforward question: what is the effect of the
- minimum wage on wages themselves? this might seem
- tautological, but if the minimum wage is low or is
- not properly enforced we may not observe an effect.
- unlike our previous figure the estimates here are
- universally positive and statistically distinct
- from zero. This is the pattern one would expect to
- observe when the relationship one is estimating
- is strong and reliable. The minimum wage effects do
- not look like this. Higher labour costs as a result
- of the minimum wage are obviously a thing. But
- employers often have more bargaining power than
- workers, so they can afford it. Increased pay can
- motivate workers, leading to higher productivity.
- It can make them more likely to stay, reducing
- turnover costs from hiring and firing.
- And at the economy-wide level, the minimum wage
- increases the spending power of workers, which
- will increase demand for businesses. I'm happy to
- debate the importance of these different effects
- but the standard economic approach only helps us
- with a tiny part of them, if at all, and arguably
- the effect on employment is so uninteresting
- that it's distracted us from other questions
- such as the effect of the minimum wage on mental
- health or poverty. So now we know that the minimum
- wage just doesn't have the kind of reliable
- negative effect on employment we'd expect if the
- theory were useful. But now i want to talk about
- another, similar, prominent example: rent control.
- It's no secret that both house prices and rents
- in many countries have skyrocketed over the past
- couple of decades, especially in Anglo countries. Housing is probably the main cost for most people
- so this has prompted questions about whether
- governments should do more to help people
- cope with these costs. The most direct
- policy to do this would be rent control.
- Rent control isn't a hugely popular policy
- although it exists in a few countries and
- localities, for example New York City as
- discussed by the friends in the popular sitcom
- 'Friends'. "But more important because of
- rent control it was a friggin' steal".
- In their debate on housing, philosopher Ben
- Burgess and streamer Destiny also discussed
- the policy: "Rent control is like one of these few
- issues that economists broadly agree is a garbage
- policy. It doesn't help who we want it to help, it
- usually hurts who we want to help and it just
- doesn't usually get what you want done." Destiny was
- correct: opposition to rent control is possibly the
- area where economists agree the most. A 1990
- poll had 93.5 percent agree that "a ceiling on
- rents reduces the quantity and quality of housing
- available". A 2012 poll asked for economists' views
- on the statement "local ordinances that limit
- rent increases for some rental housing units
- such as in New York City and San Francisco have
- had a positive effect over the past three decades
- on the amount and quality of broadly affordable
- rental housing in cities that have used them."
- 81% of economists disagreed or strongly disagreed
- with this statement with answers including "Next
- question: does the sun revolve around the earth?" "Unless all the textbooks are wrong, this is wrong"
- "The planets are lined up here: theory and
- evidence point in the same direction". The award
- for the strongest statement about rent control,
- however, goes to the economist Assar Lindbeck
- who claimed "In many cases rent control appears to
- be the most efficient technique presently known to
- destroy a city, except for bombing." To understand
- where all this strong opposition is coming from
- let's return to our supply and demand diagram. Instead of the market for labor, we are now looking
- at the market for houses. Apparently they work in
- exactly the same way. We have rents on the y-axis
- instead of wages. We also have quantity of houses
- rented on the x-axis, instead of employment. Again
- the supply and demand for houses should balance
- with rents r-star and quantity at q-star. What does
- rent control do in this situation? It's represented
- by the horizontal line RC which forces rents down.
- At this low rental rate, the quantity of houses
- supplied is lower than the previous equilibrium
- even though more people want to rent. We have a
- shortage, and a fall in rented units compared to
- the 'free market'. I want to say outright that there
- is more evidence for the predictions of the supply
- and demand model for rent control than for the
- minimum wage, depending on how you interpret it.
- But the blanket opposition to rent control that
- derives from this is hugely overstated and econ
- 101 reasoning is again more of a hindrance
- than the help for understanding the debate.
- First: what does it mean for the quantity of
- housing to be reduced? I would contend that
- the supply-demand model can mislead people into
- thinking that the reduction is in housing supply
- rather than the number of houses specifically used
- for renting. The 1990 poll mentioned above failed
- to distinguish these two clearly, and in the debate
- with Destiny, Ben Burgis just largely accepted this
- framing, contending that you could compensate by
- building more housing. "Because if we just have rent
- control there's going to be far less investment in
- private housing, there's gonna be far less private
- housing built, but if you're building a lot of
- public housing to make up the shortfall then it's
- literally- you could you could accept your premise
- you can accept what the economists are saying
- and still think that it's just irrelevant to that
- package of policies." "Why not just build more houses?"
- Building more housing is good. But a reduction in
- rental housing doesn't mean that houses disappear;
- there may just be a corresponding rise in
- ownership. Our concern is surely whether people
- are getting the houses they need, not whether
- they're renting or owning them. We can have a
- debate about the relative merits of renting
- versus ownership and which demographics are
- more likely to use one or the other, but it's not
- immediately obvious to me which is more desirable.
- Second: rent control captures a wide variety of
- different policies. The standard demand-supply
- analysis only depicts a straight-up cap on rents,
- whereas modern rent control just limits increases
- and allows for inflation in landlords' costs to
- encourage maintenance. Such provisions are common
- and common sense - for example, if you're worried
- about rent control discouraging construction
- exempt new buildings, like Berlin. Recently a
- Bloomberg article that mysteriously appeared
- in everyone's trends on Twitter discussed the
- impact of rent control in Berlin, which froze
- rents on older houses and allowed tenants to force
- landlords to lower existing rents. True to form,
- the article claims "if populism on the political
- right corrupts democracies, populism on the left
- ruins economies" It's based on a report which is in
- German and fortunately I'm fluent so I was able to
- consult the original document. Just kidding, I'm
- English. We'll have to go on the article itself.
- Some of the outcomes it chooses are kind of
- strange. The results clearly show that rents
- have plummeted for those affected, a huge benefit
- which is downplayed. The article charges that rent
- controls have reduced house prices, as if that's
- definitely a bad thing or somehow unexpected.
- It seems to me that both more affordable housing
- and lower rents might be considered a good thing
- by some people. The article uses a couple of graphs
- which apparently show the policy has had negative
- effects. One shows that prices in uncontrolled
- units have risen since the policy, but from this
- graph it's hard to see whether this is really a
- change or just a continuation of a previous trend.
- The graph doesn't go back far enough for us
- to know - and even if it is true, it may just be
- because the uncontrolled units are new. You could
- say exactly the same thing for their graph showing
- that the number of rental apartments has declined,
- especially since they follow this up with a graph
- showing that the supply of unregulated units has
- outpaced other German cities. Somehow this is also
- framed as a bad thing. As you're all now budding
- natural experiment enthusiasts I know what you're
- going to ask: is there any more credible evidence
- than this...crap...on rent control, and the answer is:
- some, but not enough, and it's mixed. One of the
- most recent and commonly cited papers on this
- topic is Diamond et. al, which uses the sudden
- introduction of rent control to older houses in
- San Francisco in 1994 and compares them with
- more recently built units which were exempt.
- Let's take an in-depth look at this paper as
- I think it raises some interesting questions.
- The paper claims that the policy led to a 15%
- reduction in rental units, although if you unpack
- this it's actually a combination of eight percent
- being converted into owner-occupied buildings
- with a further seven percent being converted into
- rental units which were exempt from rent control.
- Which isn't a 15 reduction in rental units. The
- paper does show that residents of both owner
- occupied and exempted units are likely to have
- higher income, which is a cause for concern because
- it favors richer residents. There are conflicting
- effects, though. Part of the reason for the higher
- income residents is that rent control leads to
- higher maintenance and upgrades so landlords can
- increase rents. We can see on these graphs
- that - top left - rents fell while - top right -
- redevelopments rose and - bottom left - conversions
- rose and - bottom right - repairs rose. This suggests
- rent control does increase quality, in contrast
- with economists' poll answers that we saw earlier.
- Rent control also means existing tenants are
- more likely to stay, which is more pronounced
- for minority groups. The strangest spin in the
- Diamond paper is to frame this as a bad thing too.
- Keeping existing residents in the area while rich residents join is a bad thing! The solution is obviously to have only rich residents so the income inequality in
- the area is low! "Look at this place. Somebody
- ought to build a town that works"
- "Somebody did"
- I'm being facetious, but only a little. At other
- times the paper argues that existing tenants
- are ultimately forced into poorer areas and here
- they frame gentrification as a good thing, saying
- So it's bad when existing tenants stay but also bad when they
- leave? Gentrification is good but also bad? I
- found this paper quite confusing, and it seems to
- be a go-to reference for opponents of rent control.
- With such a variety of competing effects
- the authors eventually conclude that the
- overall effects of rent control are a wash. But the
- important lesson here is that ultimately neither
- theory nor empirical analysis are going to make
- the issue of competing values and perspectives go
- away. When considering the effects of rent control,
- do we prefer rented or owned housing? Do we want
- higher quality houses which are more expensive? Do
- we want to favor existing residents over new ones?
- I don't have easy answers to these questions but
- econ 101 leads people to believe that they do.
- The economist Josh Mason argues that rent control
- research is in a similar place now to minimum wage
- research in the 1990s: a few well-formulated
- studies are displacing conventional wisdom
- and this will likely expand as time goes on. He
- summarises a few studies similar to the Diamond
- one which you can look at if you're interested in
- pursuing this topic further. So here we have two of
- the most important markets - labour and housing - where
- the crude econ 101 approach has failed to make
- sense of hotly debated policies. But what about
- more generally? Where has the influence of econ 101
- come from, and how does it affect our understanding
- of other policies like taxes and social spending?
- I don't think i can answer this one so I'm
- going to have to hand over to someone else.
- The influence of basic economics is...everywhere.
- Both pervasive and perverse, it really is why
- we cannot have nice things. For every earnest
- call to make our political economic system
- ever slightly more just or livable for working
- people or the planet there's a capitalist, an
- economist, a politician, a corporate news outlet, or
- an average joe saying "that's cute, but that's just
- not how the economy works!" James Kwak calls the
- reductive invocation of basic economics to explain
- all social phenomena in our society 'economism'. Economism relies on the abstract concepts taught
- in econ 101 classes to explain why things are
- the way they are and why any attempt to redress
- the externalities of capitalism is futile. This
- is despite the fact that many of the concepts
- taught in econ 101 textbooks assume that a
- perfectly competitive model of capitalism
- is possible, along with various other assumptions
- that rarely, if ever, hold true in the real world.
- UE covered how economism has worked to depress
- wages while housing prices have skyrocketed
- but the invocation of econ 101 has affected
- nearly every other sphere of our lives too.
- Provide universal health care as a basic human
- right? Adorable! That will rob people of choice.
- Prevent price gouging during natural disasters
- so that poor people aren't unfairly served a
- death sentence? How naive! That will prevent
- the efficiency of the competitive market from
- kicking in to save the day. Plus it'll mean
- that life-saving materials will be sold to
- people who don't value them as much as people
- who are willing to pay three times the price.
- Raise taxes on the ultra rich to redress the wage
- theft inherent in their wealth and fund services
- that will benefit everyone? So cute! Econ 101 says
- that that will backfire and lead to a decrease in
- productivity and available jobs, something that's
- never mentioned in econ 101 textbooks when talking
- about things like raising taxes on the rich or
- the minimum wage etcetera is that the ultra rich are
- hoarding money far and above what they actually
- need and they're doing so off the backs of workers
- who are the ones who actually produce the goods
- and services that make money for the capitalists.
- Workers who, like those who work for Walmart or
- McDonald's, are encouraged to apply for food stamps
- to survive. When workers are losing their homes or
- are unable to access healthcare during a pandemic
- the unwillingness of the capitalist class to pay
- taxes or living wages is pretty hard to reconcile
- - that's a polite way of putting it. But that's just
- me, let's look at how taxation and inequality plays
- out on the ground, outside of the classroom.
- Will increasing taxes on the ultra-rich
- hurt us all? In the end it follows that when you
- tax a good depending on what the good is people
- will buy less of it. But when you try to apply econ
- 101 supply and demand models to things like income
- tax the model shows us how out of touch it is with
- average working people. The model tells us that if
- income taxes are raised people will 'choose' to work
- less and take more leisure time or simply retire.
- The incentive for them to work additional hours
- is simply not there and so productivity plummets.
- For anyone actually working to survive right now
- with depressed wages and a skyrocketing housing
- market, you can see how this logic breaks down.
- People don't choose to work 60 hour work weeks;
- they desperately need to. Anyway it is true that the rich are people who
- can choose to work less if incentives aren't
- there because they are not working to survive and
- many of them are making the bulk of their income
- through investments anyway which is basically just
- sitting around and watching your assets
- grow. Taxes on capital gains and dividends
- are already much lower than income taxes but
- politicians like Paul Ryan, Marco Rubio, and Ben
- Carson invoking econ 101 want to reduce or
- eliminate taxes on investment income altogether.
- The idea is that we need rich people to save their
- money so that it can be invested somewhere else
- enabling the creation of new businesses and
- jobs. Over the past 70 years taxes on investment
- income have plummeted, with no real increase in
- economic growth and with personal savings actually
- declining. The economy expanded most rapidly in
- the 60s and 70s, when investment income tax was 70%
- or higher. Zooming into more detailed studies,
- the evidence is mixed at best. In 1978, economist
- Michael Boskin found that a tax cut that
- increases investment returns by 10 percent
- tends to result in three to four percent more
- savings. However, later studies disputed this and
- showed that those estimates depended heavily
- on contextual details. Eric Toder and Kim Rueben
- conducted a review of existing research and
- determined that there was little evidence to
- support the claim that lowering investment
- taxes increased savings. This was confirmed
- by tax expert Leonard Burman, and a Congressional
- Research Service report stated that
- This is fairly intuitive: at a certain level of wealth, people have very little else to do with their money other than invest it, regardless
- if their profits might be slightly lower. There are
- actually games now where the challenge is to spend
- all of Jeff Bezos' or Bill Gates' money, showing
- how completely impossible it is to actually buy
- enough things with that gross excess. In terms of
- productivity, working people need to work to live, period.
- But rich people - the 'job creators' - are also
- not less likely to work if income taxes are higher.
- Robert Moffitt and Mark Wilhelm studied the 1986
- tax reform and found no change in hours worked by
- high-earning men. This was confirmed by the CBO and
- economist Thomas Hungerford, who wrote:
- Growing inequality leads to growing unrest, something also not addressed in econ 101 textbooks. Despite the ample empirical
- evidence that contradicts these reductive and
- bewildering claims, economism survives and thrives
- because it is incredibly politically useful to the
- most powerful people in our society. Whenever there
- is political unrest, whenever there are militant
- movements against the violence of the status quo
- the 1 percent, the 0.1 percent will come back and say these
- well-intentioned protesters just don't understand
- basic economics. James Kwak writes that:
- So how did this idealistic ideology become so popularly accepted? Well, people
- like to point to Daddy Smith, who described the
- price mechanism and the
- Wealth of Nations in 1776, but Smith discussed many
- reasons why this principle would not hold and did
- not think that competitive market forces acting
- alone would produce the best of all possible
- worlds. Antoine-Augustin Cournot first illustrated
- supply and demand curves which were popularized
- in Alfred Marshall's 1890 textbook Principles
- of Economics. However, Marshall too rejected the
- idea that the supposed perfect equilibrium that
- was assumed to result from perfectly competitive
- markets would necessarily produce the best of all possible worlds because people will differ in wealth. He said:
- At the time in the late 19th Century, unchecked markets were
- producing immense hardship and social instability,
- leading to socialist and communist movements
- rather than any kind of embrace of pie-in-the
- sky economism. When the Great Depression hit the
- idea that unregulated markets would maximise
- universal prosperity seemed fully discredited,
- leading to a shift in economic thinking and an
- embrace of the Keynesian demand-side economics
- of the New Deal. The New Deal worked to redress
- the political conditions existing at the start of
- the 20th century, and the capitalist class started
- to resent not being able to extract as much wealth
- as possible from working people. Moneyed interests
- adopted economism and used their wealth and power
- to fund think tanks, buy politicians, buy media
- outlets and influence education so that economism
- was taken up by the broader conservative movement
- and later accepted by many liberals as well. Financing came from corporations such as General
- Motors, Ford Chrysler, General Electric, and Procter
- & Gamble among others...and billionaire businessmen
- like the Koch brothers. Ideas were derived from
- fanatic economists like Hayek, Mises, and Friedman,
- mouthpiece politicians included Reagan, Thatcher,
- Bush, Clinton - too many to name, honestly - and high
- profile think tanks like the Heritage Foundation
- lobby to influence policy. Economism allowed
- business people and politicians to say that they
- were pro-market instead of anti-government and
- conveniently ensured that labour and environmental
- concerns would be suppressed so that capitalists
- could extract more and more surplus. This is why
- David Harvey calls the neoliberal era that was
- ushered in by Reagan and Thatcher a project to
- restore elite class power. The U.S., the IMF, and the
- World Bank have also been pretty brazen in forcing
- global countries through violence and/or debt
- to deregulate their markets further and implement
- a suite of free market policies such as lowering
- or scrapping the minimum wage, which UE just
- explained makes little economic or moral sense.
- This economic imperialism served the project
- to restore transnational ruling class power
- and provided a spatial fix for capitalism.
- This is all getting into more complex
- Marxist political economy though which I
- personally think is key to understanding
- all of this so if you would like to learn
- more, might I shamelessly plug my channel?
- Why is economics 101 so pervasive as a set of
- propositions? It's kind of odd that an introductory
- diagram, based on obscenely unrealistic assumptions,
- would have so much influence, right? Well it often
- favours the rich and powerful which, as Mexie pointed
- out, isn't a bad feature for a theory to have
- if it wants to be accepted and enacted as policy. But I also think there's a more subtle force at
- play here. The reaction by Nobel Laureate James Buchanan to Card and Krueger's original finding -
- which, to remind you, was that the elasticity
- of employment with respect to minimum wage
- changes may be positive - could give
- us a clue as to what is going on:
- This statement reveals what's at stake: not just
- what is actually a fairly minor concession to
- government regulation versus the free market,
- but the very idea of economics as a science,
- with general laws that cannot be violated. Buchanan
- is right accepting these findings does amount to
- a denial that economics has scientific content
- because if markets do not obey supply and demand,
- then what hope is there? A lot of people have
- asked me to discuss healthcare on this channel
- and I'm sure I will at some point. Mexie and I have
- hopefully given you plenty of evidence that goes
- against simplistic econ101 reasoning, but the
- healthcare debate provides yet another example of
- how faulty econ101 reasoning pervades the world
- and I'm far from the only one to notice this. U.S.
- representative Alexandria Occasio-Cortez made
- the link between the two not too long ago: "When
- we talk about economics, there's something known
- as a demand curve within a elas- with elasticity.
- And with every other commodity you can say 'how
- much is this phone worth to you?' And you can
- say a hundred dollars, two hundred dollars, you can
- buy a Nokia phone, you can not have a phone at all.
- But you cannot ask the question
- 'how much will you pay to be alive?'
- 'How much will you pay to live?' Because the answer
- is everything." These kinds of examples illustrate
- that there are many reasons markets will not be as
- well behaved as the standard econ101 story. When I
- present them to economists they say a lot of words
- about how they don't really apply and that I've
- misunderstood the niceties of the theory, usually
- by defining the theory so that it simply must be
- true. But past a certain point these hypotheticals
- become useless for thinking about the real world
- and in many cases they just provide a bulwark for
- bad ideas. I want to leave you with a lengthy but
- typically eloquent quote from John Maynard Keynes
- during the Great Depression, a time when - as Mexie
- mentioned - prevailing economic orthodoxy seemed
- to be on the wane. Commenting on his version of
- economism, which he called Classical or Ricardian
- economics - after the 19th Century economist David
- Ricardo - he reflected on how it had become so
- dominant, and its likely downfall in the future:
- Thanks for listening everybody and WAIT
- just one second, before you turn it off. This has
- been a little bit of an experiment. A lot of
- people in my previous videos asked me to go
- into a bit more detail they said they'd be happy
- with a bit more length...so, this is what I've done
- in this video - it's a bit longer and it goes
- into some depth on the theory and evidence.
- I'm not saying that every video I make will
- be like this from now on but I just want to
- know what you guys think of it: was it too
- much? Do you want even more? I hope not but
- please just let me know what you think.
- And thank you to my Patrons as usual
- um there's a whole bunch of stuff that's been
- set up there's like a Discord server and a Reddit
- now if you want to discuss economics so uh
- please just get involved. See you later everybody!
- Bye!
Add Comment
Please, Sign In to add comment