Guest User

Untitled

a guest
Mar 22nd, 2018
92
0
Never
Not a member of Pastebin yet? Sign Up, it unlocks many cool features!
text 2.75 KB | None | 0 0
  1. -------- Story --------
  2.  
  3. (From Bertsekas and Tsitsiklis's Introduction_to_probability book)
  4.  
  5. A patient is admitted to the hospital and a potentially life-saving drug is administered.
  6. The following dialog takes place between the nurse and a concerned relative.
  7.  
  8. RELATIVE: Nurse, what is the probability that the drug will work?
  9.  
  10. NURSE: I hope it works, we’ll know tomorrow.
  11.  
  12. RELATIVE: Yes, but what is the probability that it will?
  13.  
  14. NURSE: Each case is different, we have to wait.
  15.  
  16. RELATIVE: But let’s see, out of a hundred patients that are treated under similar conditions,
  17. how many times would you expect it to work?
  18.  
  19. NURSE (somewhat annoyed): I told you, every person is different, for some it works, for some it doesn’t.
  20.  
  21. RELATIVE (insisting): Then tell me, if you had to bet whether it will work or not, which side of the bet would you take?
  22.  
  23. NURSE (cheering up for a moment): I’d bet it will work.
  24.  
  25. RELATIVE (somewhat relieved): OK, now, would you be willing to lose two dollars if it doesn’t work,
  26. and gain one dollar if it does?
  27.  
  28. NURSE (exasperated): What a sick thought! You are wasting my time!
  29.  
  30.  
  31. -------- Analysis -------
  32.  
  33. When nurse says " .... for some it works, for some it doesn’t ...."
  34. she is kind of indicating that there is 50-50 chance of working and not working.
  35.  
  36. If nurse accepted the bet towards the end, in her mind, she means this: Her pay off would be
  37. (assuming that probabability of drug working is p):
  38.  
  39. -2 * (1-p) + 1 (p)
  40. = -2 +2p +p
  41. = -2+3p
  42.  
  43. This has to be > 0 for her not to lose money and be happy
  44. Equivalently: p > 2/3
  45.  
  46. If p = 2/3, she does not lose or gain money: indifferent
  47.  
  48. if p < 2/3, she is unhappy (or won't to bet if she has any doubt if p < 2/3)
  49.  
  50. And, of course, the it does make sense to assign a probability value for "if the drug works on patient"
  51. once the result is known. It is either 0 or 1. But, nurse would be still indifferent/sad/happy as long as she is not
  52. revealed of the result.
  53.  
  54.  
  55. ------ Summary --------
  56.  
  57. So, if the probability of an event = p, means, this for a rational person:
  58.  
  59. He would be indifferent between the two situations:
  60.  
  61. 1) willing to bet: lose c dollars if event does not happen and gain d dollars if the event happens
  62. ( expected payoff : d * p + [ -1 * (1-p) * c ] )
  63. 2) not betting at all
  64.  
  65. Instead of being indifferent, he would be happy if d * p - c + c * p > 0
  66. or p > c / (c + d)
  67.  
  68. Instead of being indifferent, he would be sad otherwise [ or won't bet ] , i.e., p < c/(c+d)
  69.  
  70. Obviously he would be indifferent if p = c / (c+d)
  71.  
  72. And, of course, once the event takes places (or does not),
  73. P(event) does not make sense as we know the result for sure: 0 or 1. But the rational person's state of
  74. mind is still the same as long as he is not revealed of the outcome.
  75.  
  76. ---------- End of story ---------
Add Comment
Please, Sign In to add comment