Advertisement
Guest User

Untitled

a guest
May 25th, 2018
237
0
Never
Not a member of Pastebin yet? Sign Up, it unlocks many cool features!
text 38.88 KB | None | 0 0
  1. Mobility and
  2. Entrepreneurship:
  3. Evaluating the Scope of
  4. Knowledge-Based
  5. Theories of
  6. Entrepreneurship
  7. Lars Frederiksen
  8. Karl Wennberg
  9. Chanchal Balachandran
  10. Knowledge-based theories of entrepreneurship infer transfer of knowledge from the
  11. effect of labor mobility on entrepreneurial entry. Yet, simple selection or situational
  12. mechanisms that do not imply knowledge transfer may influence entrepreneurial entry in
  13. similar ways. We argue that the extent to which such alternative mechanisms operate,
  14. labor mobility predicts entry but not subsequent performance for entrepreneurs. Analyses
  15. of matched employee–employer data from Sweden suggest that high rates of geographical
  16. and industry mobility increase individuals’ likelihood of entrepreneurial entry
  17. but have no effects on their entrepreneurial performance. This indicates that the relationship
  18. between labor mobility and entrepreneurial entry do not necessarily imply knowledge
  19. transfer.
  20. The flow of people between firms, industries and locations has been proposed as an
  21. important mechanism for transferring knowledge1 and is argued as important for innovation,
  22. firm demography, and entrepreneurship (e.g., Agarwal, Echambadi, Franco, &
  23. Sarkar, 2004; Audretsch & Keilback, 2007). For entrepreneurship research, individual
  24. mobility is central since it invokes the creation, transfer, and destruction of resources and
  25. capabilities in different markets (Wright, 2011). While knowledge-based theories propose
  26. knowledge flow as the key mechanism that connects labor mobility to entrepreneurial
  27. entry and performance (Agarwal, Audretsch, & Sarkar, 2007; Helfat & Lieberman,
  28. 2002), they are rarely challenged by alternative selection-based mechanisms such as individual
  29. “taste for variety” or “labor market misfits” (A˚stebro, Chen, & Thompson, 2011;
  30. Please send correspondence to: Karl Wennberg, tel.: 146-705-10 53 66; email: karl.wennberg@liu.se.
  31. 1. Following theories of knowledge spillover, we refer to “knowledge” as an appropriable resource that is
  32. distinct from individual “skills” (Audretsch & Keilback, 2007).
  33. March, 2016 359
  34. DOI: 10.1111/etap.12223
  35. 1042-2587
  36. VC 2016 The Authors. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice published
  37. by Wiley Periodicals, Inc. on behalf of SAGE Publications Inc.
  38. This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative
  39. Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs License, which permits
  40. use and distribution in any medium, provided the original work is
  41. properly cited, the use is non-commercial and no modifications or
  42. adaptations are made.
  43. A˚stebro & Thompson, 2011) and situational mechanisms2 such as individual opportunity
  44. cost (Amit, Muller, & Cockburn, 1995; Sørensen & Fassiotto, 2011). To the extent selection
  45. or situational factors explain the relationship between labor market mobility and
  46. entrepreneurship, knowledge-based theories that infer a treatment effect of knowledge
  47. transfer on entrepreneurship entry may be overestimated. While we expect to find a positive
  48. effect of labor market mobility on entrepreneurial entry through selection or situational
  49. mechanisms, we also expect to find an adverse or no effect on entrepreneurial
  50. performance if knowledge transfer is not the key mechanism underlying entrepreneurial
  51. entry. The basis of our argument is the assumption that knowledge is a key predictor of
  52. entrepreneurial performance (Agarwal et al., 2004; Dencker, Gruber, & Shah, 2009;
  53. Helfat & Lieberman; Klepper & Sleeper, 2005). We test our arguments by analyzing the
  54. effect of different types of mobility on entrepreneurial entry and entrepreneurial performance
  55. relative to post-entry earnings.
  56. We posit two research questions. The first question regards pre-founding characteristics
  57. of entrepreneurs: To what extent does prior industry and geographical mobility influence
  58. individuals’ propensity to found a new firm? We argue that certain individual
  59. characteristics in combination with the opportunity structure they confront may explain
  60. entry into entrepreneurship. First, highly mobile individuals have a taste for variety or are
  61. misfits in the labor market that position them in constant search for new jobs. As jobs in
  62. established organizations tend to be standardized, individuals with a taste for variety are
  63. likely to enter entrepreneurship in search for different job experiences. Second, interindustry
  64. mobility provides opportunity for information arbitrage or results in low average
  65. industry specific experience, reducing the opportunity cost of switching from employment
  66. to entrepreneurship. Thus, a combination of selection and situational mechanisms
  67. may drive mobility into entrepreneurship without necessarily being accompanied by
  68. knowledge transfer.
  69. To examine our claim that entry into entrepreneurship of highly mobile individuals
  70. may be driven by selection and situational mechanisms, we test the relationship between
  71. mobility and entrepreneurial performance. Knowledge-based theory of entrepreneurship
  72. posits individual mobility as a focal mechanism through which knowledge created in
  73. established organizations flows to newly founded firms (Agarwal et al., 2007; Franco &
  74. Filson, 2006; Saxenian, 2006). If the flow of valuable knowledge is what drives entrepreneurship
  75. through employee mobility, then we should also expect systematic difference in
  76. the performance of entrepreneurs established by highly mobile individuals and those who
  77. experienced less mobility across jobs and industries. Alternatively, individuals who enter
  78. entrepreneurship simply because of their innate characteristics or the low opportunity
  79. cost in leaving paid employment do not necessarily transfer valuable knowledge predictive
  80. of entrepreneurial performance (Amit et al., 1995). These alternative explanations
  81. suggest that while mobile individuals are more likely to enter entrepreneurship, they do
  82. not necessarily exhibit better performance as entrepreneurs. Hence, our second question
  83. is: How does prior job mobility of firm founders affect entrepreneurial performance?
  84. To investigate these questions, we use matched employee–employer data that follows
  85. individuals and firms in Sweden over 11 years. This enables us to pinpoint pre-founding
  86. effects on individuals arriving into entrepreneurship (e.g., spawning firm characteristics)
  87. and their career histories, allowing us to construct detailed measures of individual
  88. 2. Situational mechanisms pertain to the structure of opportunities an individual faces while selecting from
  89. a set of choices (Hedstr€om & Swedberg, 1998). As such, we do not assume any changes in the individual,
  90. for example, through learning, as a result of mobility.
  91. 360 ENTREPRENEURSHIP THEORY and PRACTICE
  92. mobility (A˚stebro & Thompson, 2011). As we are interested in evaluating the scope of
  93. knowledge-based theories we zoom in on a subsample of industries where knowledge is
  94. of vital importance: knowledge-intensive industries.3 These industries serve as an ideal
  95. research setting to test our argument regarding knowledge flows, entrepreneurial entry,
  96. and performance. First, since knowledge is central to innovation and imitation in products
  97. and services as well as a key determinant of entrepreneurship (Delmar & Wennberg,
  98. 2010), knowledge-intensive industry is a suitable setting in which to test our arguments.
  99. Second, prior studies on knowledge-based theories of entrepreneurship mostly relied on
  100. data from knowledge-intensive industries such as laser (Klepper & Sleeper, 2005) or
  101. disk-drive industries (Agarwal et al., 2004) etc., whereby these industries serve as a natural
  102. setting for comparison. Third, focusing on this setting minimizes the unobserved heterogeneity
  103. issues surrounding industry differences in studying the rates of
  104. entrepreneurship (Eckhardt & Shane, 2011).4
  105. Our work seeks to bring clarity into the mechanisms that tie mobility to entrepreneurship.
  106. While knowledge-based theories of entrepreneurship posit knowledge transfer as a
  107. key mechanism that drives entrepreneurship (Acs, Braunerhjelm, Audretsch, & Carlsson,
  108. 2009; Agarwal et al., 2007), we show that it may not necessarily always be true. We found
  109. that pre-founding job mobility affects the prevalence of entrepreneurial entry but not the
  110. earnings of entrepreneurs. Our results on differential effects of mobility on entrepreneurial
  111. entry and earnings provide a note of caution to researchers: Resources and knowledge
  112. may not be automatically inferred to flow from mobility without considering simple counterfactuals
  113. such as individuals’ innate taste for variety (A˚stebro & Thompson, 2011) or
  114. the opportunity structure they confront (Sørensen & Sharkey, 2014). Without attending to
  115. simple explanations related to selection or situational effects, models that attribute knowledge
  116. transfer as a mechanism that drive mobility into entrepreneurship will risk overestimation.
  117. As a corollary, our research also speaks to the expanding research on “firm
  118. spawning” (e.g., Klepper & Sleeper, 2005; Sørensen & Phillips, 2011), by showing that
  119. the “small firm spawning effect” documented in prior studies exercises differential effects
  120. on entrepreneurial entry and earnings in knowledge-intensive industries.
  121. Theory and Hypotheses
  122. We offer five hypotheses to probe different mechanisms related to the effect of labor
  123. market mobility of individuals on entrepreneurial entry and performance. We structure
  124. the hypotheses development in a way that highlights the limitations of inferring knowledge
  125. flows from the effect of mobility on entrepreneurship. We do this by contrasting
  126. knowledge-based explanations with alternative explanations based on selection and situational
  127. mechanisms, such as taste for variety, labor market misfits, and opportunity cost.
  128. Mobility and Entry into Entrepreneurship
  129. Why are individuals with a high degree of industry mobility more likely to found a
  130. firm than individuals with less mobility in their career history? Typical arguments refer to
  131. knowledge accumulation and spillover effects as mechanisms by which highly mobile
  132. 3. Please see the Methods section and the Appendix for definitions and descriptions of these industries.
  133. 4. While the data allow us to investigate instances where prospective entrepreneurs venture into other industries
  134. (Agarwal et al., 2004), our results are not exhaustive to entrepreneurship in all potential industries.
  135. March, 2016 361
  136. individuals enter entrepreneurship (e.g., Agarwal et al., 2004). Yet, part of the reason can
  137. be attributed to the possibility that certain individual characteristics such as taste for
  138. variety are correlated with their propensity for mobility. Ghiselli (1974, p. 81) suggests
  139. the idea of the hobo effect as “...the periodic itch to move from a job in one place to some
  140. other job in some other place.”5 If individuals with a high degree of mobility are primarily
  141. driven by a taste for variety, they may have a psychological bias against staying in regular
  142. jobs for long periods of time (A˚stebro & Thompson, 2011). As a result of constant search
  143. for varied experience, they also exhibit a certain degree of misfit in the labor market.
  144. Such underlying individual characteristics could affect individuals’ choice for entrepreneurial
  145. entry, working independently from a change in their knowledge pool. Hence,
  146. selection on unobserved traits may explain both mobility and entry into entrepreneurship
  147. without any treatment effect of knowledge transfer.
  148. Mobility and entry into entrepreneurship may also be codetermined by situational
  149. mechanisms such as individual opportunity structure. First, individuals who transfer
  150. between industries are more likely to identify niche opportunities in the market as well as
  151. to engage in arbitrage of information, which is asymmetrically distributed in society
  152. (Shane, 2000). Aldrich and Kenworthy (1999, p. 20) argue that “... innovative start-ups
  153. are often the result of creative experimentation with new ideas by outsiders to an industry.
  154. Experience guides the choice of a domain for exploration, but indifference to industry
  155. routines and norms gives an outsider the freedom to break free of the cognitive constraints
  156. on incumbents.” As mobility helps individuals to identify opportunities, we can expect a
  157. positive effect of mobility on entrepreneurial entry without actually having any changes
  158. in their knowledge pool.
  159. Second, highly mobile individuals may lower opportunity cost in entering entrepreneurship
  160. (Amit et al., 1995). While moving from one industry to another, individuals
  161. forego industry-specific skills that would otherwise contribute to their human capital. The
  162. loss of human capital associated with switching industries reduces their seniority for
  163. which they may incur a wage penalty in the labor market. As a result, highly mobile individuals
  164. have less incentive to search for jobs in established firms, resulting in increased
  165. mobility into entrepreneurship.
  166. Third, situational mechanisms (e.g., opportunity for information arbitrage, opportunity
  167. cost) may interact with selection mechanisms (e.g., taste for variety, labor market
  168. misfits) in driving entry into entrepreneurship without any knowledge diffusion. For
  169. instance, opportunity for arbitrage is more likely to be utilized by individuals with a taste
  170. for variety. They are less likely to be satisfied with accumulating skills and competences
  171. related to a particular industry. Continuous search for different experiences would predispose
  172. them to experiment with entrepreneurship because the set of available jobs in an
  173. industry may not remain attractive long enough for such individuals. The innate taste for
  174. varied experience will likely make them misfits in any labor market that operates with
  175. institutionally defined roles and knowledge structures (e.g., professional boundaries),
  176. making them more susceptible to respond to opportunity structures. Taken together we
  177. posit:
  178. 5. Ghiselli (1974, p. 81) continues: “This urge to move seems not to result from organized or logical
  179. thought, but rather would appear more akin to raw, surging, internal impulses, perhaps not unlike those that
  180. cause birds to migrate. Floaters readily provide socially acceptable explanations for their peripatetic activity,
  181. but under careful examination these explanations turn out to be little more than rationalizations. The simple
  182. fact is that after being in one place for a matter of months, or perhaps a year or so, depending on the strength
  183. and periodicity of his itch, the individual is impelled to pack up and move to another place and another job.”
  184. 362 ENTREPRENEURSHIP THEORY and PRACTICE
  185. Hypothesis 1: The number of different industries within which an individual has
  186. held a job is positively related to an individual’s likelihood of entrepreneurial
  187. entry.
  188. To further investigate the effect of mobility on entrepreneurial entry, we hypothesize
  189. another dimension of mobility—across geographical regions. Geographical mobility as a
  190. mechanism for knowledge spillovers in entrepreneurship is primarily studied from the
  191. network or internationalization perspectives: for example, how entrepreneurs starting
  192. businesses in their local environment can draw on local resources and relationships
  193. (Stuart & Sørenson, 2003) or how immigrants and expatriates who move from, or back to,
  194. their home country set up businesses in new regions (Saxenian, 2006). As such, we know
  195. less about more general types of geographic mobility—that of individuals within national
  196. boundaries—as a mechanism regulating the propensity for entrepreneurial entry. Out-ofarea
  197. moves entail disruption to social resources and roles, altering the locations of life
  198. and work. Such moves are often provoked by dissatisfaction with current work or life
  199. states, or by the lure of more attractive work or life situations elsewhere. This typically
  200. means that while some individuals move to start businesses in remote regions where
  201. industry conditions are fertile, most entrepreneurs choose to start businesses in the region
  202. in which their social network is embedded (Cooper, 1985).
  203. The social network perspective—frequent in studies of transnational entrepreneurship
  204. as well as on entrepreneurial opportunity discovery—suggests two types of mechanisms
  205. whereby geographical mobility may trigger entrepreneurship: First, moving out of
  206. their original location exposes individuals to new types of opportunities, which they may
  207. be able to recognize and develop. The movement from far away may enhance the possibility
  208. for bringing new skills and ideas into a context that may value such “foreign” and
  209. different products or services (Davidsson, 2004).
  210. Second, a diverse geographical background with time spent in a number of locations
  211. provides opportunities for building an expanded social network in terms of “weak ties” to
  212. a variety of potential customers, suppliers, and other stakeholder. Newcomers in a region
  213. that have a significant range of weak ties are ideally positioned for information arbitrage
  214. and thereby the discovery of entrepreneurial opportunities (Kim & Aldrich, 2007). A high
  215. degree of geographical mobility may thus enhance individuals’ network resources as well
  216. as their cognitive base for identifying opportunities (Saxenian, 2006), leading us to
  217. suggest:
  218. Hypothesis 2a: The number of moves between different geographic areas is positively
  219. related to an individual’s likelihood of entrepreneurial entry.
  220. Hypothesis 2b: The distance of geographic moves is positively related to an
  221. individual’s likelihood of entrepreneurial entry.
  222. Mobility and Entrepreneurial Performance
  223. If mobility between different industries or locations leads to accumulation of knowledge,
  224. mobility should not only influence the likelihood of entrepreneurial entry but could
  225. also influence entrepreneurial performance. Given the counterfactual possibility that reasons
  226. for mobility are driven by situational or selection mechanisms, examining the effects
  227. March, 2016 363
  228. of mobility on entrepreneurial performance provides an interesting litmus test of
  229. knowledge-based arguments. If mobility is strongly associated with some other background
  230. variable that does not affect entrepreneurial success, we would expect mobility to
  231. exhibit a positive effect on entrepreneurial entry but exhibit no effect—or even an adverse
  232. effect—on entrepreneurial earning.
  233. If movement across different industries and locations is prompted by an individual’s
  234. taste for variety, this may, however, have detrimental effects on entrepreneurial capabilities
  235. from too frequent job shifts (Elfenbein, Hamilton, & Zenger, 2010). In fact, this may
  236. be detrimental for human capital accumulation, since a fair length of tenure is required to
  237. learn any job and thus accumulate knowledge. Better performance in entrepreneurship
  238. usually requires in-depth knowledge regarding the needs of the market and meeting those
  239. demands with sufficient quality in technical or product-related competences, skills that
  240. are often acquired through education or accumulated industry experience (Dahl &
  241. Reichstein, 2007). For instance, in a study of the invention of three-dimensional (3D)
  242. printing, Shane (2000) argues that exploitation of entrepreneurial opportunity in 3D printing
  243. is influenced by the extent to which entrepreneurs acquired prior knowledge related to
  244. the technology and their familiarity with market needs and potential customers.
  245. Yet another alternative explanation is that mobile individuals may have difficulties in
  246. finding a good “match” in either paid employment or entrepreneurship (A˚stebro et al.,
  247. 2011). They simply may have abilities that are ill-suited for employment or have less ability
  248. to work well with others. Both alternative explanations (i.e., taste for variety and labor
  249. market misfits) suggest that if knowledge is not driving the mobility–entrepreneurship
  250. relationship, we would observe mobile individuals to be more likely to enter entrepreneurship
  251. but not exhibit higher performance:
  252. Hypothesis 3a: The number of different industries within which an entrepreneur
  253. has held a job has a negative or zero association with entrepreneurial performance.
  254. Hypothesis 3b: The number of moves between different geographic areas made by
  255. an entrepreneur has a negative or zero association with entrepreneurial performance.
  256. Data and Methods
  257. Responding to pleas in entrepreneurship research to use longitudinal data that does
  258. not depend on success or recall bias we employ an extract from a set of two matched longitudinal
  259. data sources on the Swedish labor market to test our hypotheses. Our data come
  260. from governmental registers maintained for research purposes by Statistics Sweden. The
  261. first source is LISA—a database on all legal residents of Sweden over the age of 16 from
  262. 1989 onwards. It contains demographic and financial information from a number of sources,
  263. including individual tax statements, financial records, birthplace registries, and
  264. school records. The second source is RAMS—an annual mandatory survey of the total
  265. population of all legal residents matched to firms having at least one employee or earning
  266. a profit. This source offers information on employment, industrial structures, and also
  267. tracks flows in the labor market.
  268. The sample frame of our database is the complete set of individuals and firms in
  269. knowledge-intensive industries, according to Eurostat and OECD classifications of such
  270. sectors (G€otzfried, 2004). In total, twenty-two 5-digit industry codes equivalent to the
  271. 364 ENTREPRENEURSHIP THEORY and PRACTICE
  272. U.S. Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) system are included in the sample, comprising
  273. 33% of the Swedish economy but over 40% of GDP (see the Appendix). While only
  274. individuals active in these industries at any time from 1989 to 2002 are included, we have
  275. complete labor market history on these individuals regardless of their prior employment
  276. industry, and we continue to observe individuals that move to other industries. Hence,
  277. while our inferences with regards to entrepreneurial entry and earnings are limited to ventures
  278. in knowledge-intensive industries, the measures of mobility are unbiased. These
  279. matched databases enable us to observe transitions in labor status and the characteristics
  280. of firms in which individuals have been employed and/or founded. Important for our purposes,
  281. the data permit us to observe the career trajectory of individuals transcending from
  282. employment into entrepreneurship.6
  283. The construction of the sample for analysis was based on a set of restrictions from the
  284. LISA data set to eliminate sources of heterogeneity. First, to avoid potential biases from
  285. situations where gender may impact family choices on entrepreneurship entry and performance,
  286. we included only men in our sample. Second, we exclude those with any experience
  287. in entrepreneurship between 1989 and 1994, since the dynamics of serial
  288. entrepreneurship is known to be distinct from that of novice entrepreneurs (Ucbasaran,
  289. Westhead, & Wright, 2009), which could bias our estimates of mobility. Third, to develop
  290. measures of pre-entry labor market experience we eliminate observations prior to 1994
  291. (Sørensen & Phillips, 2011). Finally, to avoid problems of retirement and full-time education,
  292. we eliminate all individuals who exit the labor force any time between 1995 and
  293. 2001, and further eliminate all below age 23 or above age 65 in any of the years 1994 to
  294. 2001.
  295. In total, 230,362 individuals fulfill our sample criteria. We follow these from 1994
  296. until 2002 and include their labor market history between 1989 and 1994 to construct predictor
  297. and control variables. The long time period of the data addresses the challenge in
  298. studying career histories and mobility over time (Carroll & Mosakowski, 1987).
  299. Dependent Variables
  300. We model two key outcomes in entrepreneurship research: entrepreneurial entry in
  301. the form of creating a new legal organization (Shane, 2009) and entrepreneurial performance
  302. measured as firm founder’s income from entrepreneurship.
  303. Following earlier research, the first dependent variable, entry, is a dichotomous indicator
  304. of whether an individual in our population was active in entrepreneurship during
  305. year t, but not in the preceding year (Sørensen & Phillips, 2011). We define an entrepreneur
  306. as an individual who reports residual income from a company in which she works
  307. full time. To exclude the prevalence of part-time or “hybrid” entrepreneurs (Folta,
  308. Delmar, & Wennberg, 2010) we include only firms where the individual also holds the
  309. majority ownership stake.
  310. The second dependent variable is Entrepreneurial performance. We measure performance
  311. using entrepreneurial earnings. Prior studies have exhibited difficulties in measuring
  312. firm performance since performance in entrepreneurship is difficult to collect for
  313. discontinued ventures. Performance has often been ignored or measured indirectly as
  314. “financial leverage” (Bates, 1990) or “money taken out of the business” (Gimeno, Folta,
  315. Cooper, & Woo, 1997). These are imperfect measures since entrepreneurs often choose to
  316. 6. A somewhat similar approach is taken by papers investigating related issues using generalizable longitudinal
  317. data on the U.S. (Ozcan & Reichstein, 2009) or Danish labor markets (Nanda & Sørensen, 2010). €
  318. March, 2016 365
  319. forego current benefits in preference of reinvesting the money. We overcome this problem
  320. by using the multi-level nature of the data, where firm-level performance variables
  321. can be constructed according to Hamilton’s (2000) definition of entrepreneurial earnings
  322. as (revenues – expenses 5 money taken out 1 retained earnings), where performance is
  323. measured as the sum of money taken out 1 retained earnings. The measure was highly
  324. skewed and we therefore transformed it into log form.
  325. Job Switch. To account for the possibility that mobility may be related to any type of
  326. job switch (including entrepreneurial entry) we also model Job switch, defined as leaving
  327. paid employment and moving to another employer between year t and the preceding year.
  328. This provides a counterfactual to the test of our mobility variables for entrepreneurial
  329. entry.
  330. Independent Variables
  331. Industry Mobility. Movement across industrial sectors exposes the individual to a wider
  332. range of tasks and organizational models, thus extending the individual’s experience in
  333. terms of scope. Using LISA, we count the number of job moves between different industry
  334. domains (i.e., across 5-digit SIC codes) an individual has experienced during the past
  335. 5 years.7
  336. LISA includes information on individuals’ county of residence and how often
  337. addresses are updated. We used this information to create two variables. Geographical
  338. mobility is an ordinal-scaled variable counting the number of times an individual has
  339. moved between municipalities during the past 5 years.8 Geographical mobility distance
  340. measures the accumulated distance that an individual has moved during the past 5 years,
  341. using a variant of the geographic dispersion index developed by Sørenson and Audia
  342. (2000). A higher value of this measure implies high geographical mobility; lower values
  343. imply low mobility.
  344. Control Variables
  345. Our argument that mobility matters for entrepreneurship hinges on the proposition
  346. that it is not exclusively either: (1) the traditional time-invariant variables like gender or
  347. age, or (2) human and social capital parameters such as education levels, experience of
  348. previous entrepreneurial endeavors, having entrepreneurial parents, or exposure to particular
  349. peers or even (3) the life-course variables of marriage and children—that best predict
  350. the potential for entrepreneurship. To address concerns that our results are caused by
  351. 7. We included a squared term to investigate the potential nonlinear effects of industry mobility to further
  352. probe the “taste for variety” argument. This variable was not statistically significant but highly collinear
  353. with the industry mobility variable. We therefore report models without the nonlinear effect of industry
  354. mobility as not to overfit our model and induce risks of multicolinearity. As a robustness test, we categorized
  355. industry mobility only when shifts occurred in two-digit SIC codes. This decreases the variable’s mean
  356. value from 1.36 to 1.03 and the maximum value from 11 to 7 but in our Cox models it was still a positively
  357. associated with entrepreneurial entry (p > .001) but not significantly related to performance (p < .10).
  358. 8. Using industry and geographic mobility as independent variables has an additional advantage in disentangling
  359. entrepreneurship entry from being a random outcome of mobility in general. While industry switches
  360. will alter the opportunity cost of entrepreneurship entry because of the loss of industry-specific human capital,
  361. geographic mobility is weakly correlated with job mobility in our setting (Korpi, Clark, & Malmberg, 2011).
  362. 366 ENTREPRENEURSHIP THEORY and PRACTICE
  363. other effects we include a number of additional control variables, which have been shown
  364. in previous studies to influence entrepreneurial entry and performance.
  365. Employer size is found to influence the probability of entrepreneurial entry (Sørensen,
  366. 2007a). We measure size of prior employer organization with five dummy variables
  367. where the first indicates employer size 1–25, the second indicates employer size 26–100,
  368. the third employer size 101–1,000, the fourth employer size 1,001–5,000, and the fifth
  369. (omitted as baseline in regression) for employer size 5,0001. Employer age is measured
  370. with two dummy variables since our data is left censored at 1989. The first denotes
  371. employer age 0–2 and the second denotes employer age 3–6. Work tenure is captured by a
  372. variable measuring the number of years of employment since entering “time at risk”—
  373. i.e., 1994. By nature of the sample set-up, this key variable is not truncated. Hence, the
  374. variable takes the value between 1 and 5. We also include its squared effect: work tenure
  375. squared, to control for potential nonlinear effects.9 We include a variable Years of education
  376. to operationalize general human capital (Arum & M€uller, 2004; Br€uderl, Preisend€orfer,
  377. & Ziegler, 1992). To remedy the risk of our mobility variable being confounded with
  378. the accumulation of specific human capital, we created the variable Industry experience,
  379. measured as number of years of experience in a focal industry (SIC-3 level equivalent)
  380. during the 5 most recent years of an individuals’ career. The variable was thus truncated
  381. above 5. Truncation of independent variables risks underestimating the effect of the variance
  382. in the variable at the positive side of the distribution and increases the likelihood of
  383. type-two errors. However, only 3% of the sample had 5 years or more industry experience,
  384. indicating low risk of systematic bias.10
  385. The choice to set up a new firm may be affected by parental heritage; that is, a child
  386. following the career footsteps of his or her parents (Evans & Leighton, 1989). Parental
  387. heritage is known to affect entrepreneurial entry through transfer of human capital, exposure
  388. to role models, and inheritance of genetic disposition (Aldrich & Ruef, 2006;
  389. Sørensen, 2007b). To control for this we include a dummy variable, Parents’ entrepreneurship,
  390. measuring exposure to entrepreneurship during upbringing. This variable is
  391. derived from Statistics Sweden’s cross-generation database that provides data on the
  392. labor market activities of all Swedish residents living in the same household from 1960 to
  393. 2002.
  394. Children: A time-variant ordinal variable measures number of children in the household.
  395. Married: We used information on household composition from LISA to construct a
  396. dummy variable that equals 1 if the individual is married or cohabiting. Ethnic background:
  397. Immigrants are known to have higher probabilities of entering entrepreneurship
  398. (Arum & M€uller, 2004). We measure immigration with a dummy that takes the value 0
  399. for Nordic (i.e., Scandinavian) and 15 other. Wage as employee is measured in logarithmic
  400. form to control for the opportunity costs of employment (Ozcan & Reichstein, 2009). €
  401. Spouse wage is measured in logarithmic form to control for the fact that household
  402. resources are often pooled in entrepreneurial firms (Folta et al., 2010). Household wealth
  403. is a dummy variable taking the value “1” if a person has assets (including a house)
  404. exceeding $110,000, which controls for the potential of liquidity affecting likelihood of
  405. entry. All individuals living in Sweden receive a personal identification number based on
  406. their date of birth. We used this information to calculate individual’s Age (in years).
  407. 9. The squared term of work tenure is highly collinear with the constitutive term. In unreported models—
  408. available on request—we therefore included only the constitutive term, with results unchanged.
  409. 10. As robustness checks we fitted unreported models including a dummy variable for individuals with 61
  410. years of experience. This slightly decreased effects sizes but significance levels were still well below 5%.
  411. March, 2016 367
  412. Our theory posits an alternative to knowledge spillover argument for departures from
  413. wage work to entrepreneurship, yet we cannot distinguish between departures driven by a
  414. “taste for variety” and low opportunity costs in terms of low/stagnating wages. To proxy for
  415. the potential of necessity-driven departures from employment to entrepreneurship by
  416. employees, we include the control variable Wage trend, coded as an accumulated 3-year
  417. change in wage. For most individuals, this variable takes a positive value but for some it
  418. takes a negative value, indicating falling wages. This variable approximates for the opportunity
  419. costs of leaving paid employment for entrepreneurship. Inverse Mills Ratio; In our
  420. data, 2,549 individuals engage in entrepreneurship at any time during the period 1995 to
  421. 2002. Our analysis of entrepreneurial performance is based solely on these individuals, who
  422. constitute a subsample of the overall group of potential entrepreneurs. It is possible that this
  423. subsample exhibits some specific characteristics that simultaneously affect their likelihood
  424. of engaging in entrepreneurship and their performance as entrepreneurs, raising a risk that
  425. coefficients that show a statistically significant relationship with subsequent performance
  426. will be biased. We approached that aspect of the subsample by using a two-step Heckman
  427. process where the estimates of entrepreneurial entry in Table 3 are used as a self-selection
  428. control for entry when estimating the performance equation. We used Lee’s (1983) generalization
  429. of the Heckman selection model to create a selection-correction variable (Inverse
  430. Mills Ratio) from the predicted estimates of entrepreneurial entry in Table 3. As instrument
  431. for the selection equation, we excluded the variables: Wage trend, Wage, and Spouse wage,
  432. all of which were significantly related to likelihood of entry but only very weakly related to
  433. entrepreneurial performance. Introducing the Inverse Mills Ratio in Table 4 lowers the risk
  434. of observing spurious results based on sample selection bias. All predictor and control variables
  435. were lagged 1 year to avoid simultaneity bias.
  436. Estimation Strategy
  437. Our first set of analyses uses competing hazard rate analysis to estimate models of
  438. entrepreneurial entry, compared to taking a new job (Br€uderl et al., 1992). The flexible Cox
  439. specification is used, which does not require specific assumptions in regards to the distribution
  440. of the hazard rate (Lancaster, 1979).11 Cox regression models time (t) as a function of
  441. an underlying hazard h and a set of exponentiated beta coefficients (bij) and covariates (x)
  442. for individual at year. The baseline hazard h corresponds to the case where all covariates
  443. (x) equals 0, and is shifted up or down proportionally with changes in the covariates:
  444. h tð Þ5h0ð Þt exp bijxij (1)
  445. The standard Cox model does not account for the potential of unobservables in the data.
  446. The presence of unobserved heterogeneity is conceivable in entrepreneurship due to the
  447. unobservable nature of entrepreneurial skills, which may be uncorrelated with observable
  448. skills (Parker, 2005; Shane, 2000).12 The problem of unobserved heterogeneity—called
  449. 11. We plotted the data to ensure the proportional-hazards assumptions were met. We also plotted baseline
  450. Kaplan–Meier survival curves for all hypothesized variables and compared these with the curves predicted
  451. by the Cox models to ensure that predicted effects did not deviate abnormally from observed values.
  452. 12. Our sample is designed to restrict heterogeneity in, e.g., prior entrepreneurial experiences and gender to
  453. test the theoretical variables of mobility and prior employment. We still cannot rule out the presence of
  454. unobserved heterogeneity. A common remedy to the problem of unobserved heterogeneity is to estimate
  455. models with individual fixed effects. However, by the nature of our design individuals may enter entrepreneurship
  456. only once and as a consequence, fixed effects cannot be utilized (Sørensen & Phillips, 2011).
  457. 368 ENTREPRENEURSHIP THEORY and PRACTICE
  458. “frailty” in hazard analysis—tends to stem from incomplete model specification
  459. where models with no frailty are at risk overestimating negative time dependence in
  460. the hazard rate, as well as underestimating the proportionate effect on the hazard
  461. from a change in the predictors (Lancaster, 1979). Hazard models can be extended to
  462. account for heterogeneity by incorporating frailty as a latent random effect that enters
  463. multiplicatively on the hazard function. We try to accommodate the existence of
  464. unobserved heterogeneity (frailty) by estimating a version of the Cox model which
  465. incorporates a gamma distributed random effects term with mean zero to summarize
  466. unobserved frailty connected to each individual spell. The random effects are speci-
  467. fied to arise randomly but stratified according to some observable group characteristics
  468. that may be correlated with unobservable characteristics. Entrepreneurial ability
  469. is generally believed to be correlated with education and other human capital variables.
  470. We, therefore, stratified individuals according to years of education (17 groups)
  471. since educational level is known to be correlated with both IQ and unobserved ability
  472. (Van Praag & Cramer, 2001).13 In the model estimated, the random effects term (v)
  473. describes unexplained heterogeneity as the influence of unobserved risk factors in the
  474. model as:
  475. hijð Þt 5h0ð Þt exp bijxij1vi
  476. (2)
  477. In the regression outputs, all coefficients are displayed as hazard rates (HR), which
  478. ease interpretation of these as marginal effects. These we attend to for each hypothesis. A
  479. coefficient of 1.01 indicates that a one-unit increase in covariate x increases the likelihood
  480. of the outcome variable (entry or exit) with 1%, while .99 indicate that a one-unit increase
  481. in covariate x decreases the likelihood of the outcome variable with 1%.
  482. In the second set of analyses, we apply linear regression models to examine the
  483. effects of theoretically motivated mobility variables for entrepreneurial performance.
  484. These models are estimated using two different specifications, pooled OLS, and panel
  485. data models estimated with random effects. Both models were estimated with standard
  486. errors clustered around individuals to accommodate for autocorrelation.
Advertisement
Add Comment
Please, Sign In to add comment
Advertisement