Advertisement
Guest User

Passage from "Towards a New Socialism"

a guest
Jul 24th, 2017
113
0
Never
Not a member of Pastebin yet? Sign Up, it unlocks many cool features!
text 7.16 KB | None | 0 0
  1. Here we base ourselves on the classical Marxist analysis of society. In Marx’s
  2. view, the most basic distinguishing feature of different modes of social organi-
  3. sation is the manner in which they ensure the ‘extraction of a surplus product’
  4. from the direct producers. This requires a little explanation. The ‘necessary
  5. product’, on this theory, is the product required to maintain and reproduce the
  6. workforce itself. This will take the form of consumer goods and services for the
  7. workers and their families, and the investment in plant, equipment and so on
  8. that is needed simply to maintain the society’s means of production in working
  9. order. The ‘surplus product’, on the other hand, is that portion of social output
  10. used to maintain the non-producing members of society (a heterogeneous lot,
  11. ranging from the idle rich, to politicians, to the armed forces, to retired working
  12. people), plus that portion devoted to net expansion of the stock of means of
  13. production. Any society capable of supporting non-producing members, and
  14. of generating an economically progressive programme of net investment, must
  15. have some mechanism for compelling or inducing the direct producers to pro-
  16. duce more than is needed simply to maintain themselves. The precise nature of
  17. this mechanism is, according to Marxist theory, the key to understanding the
  18. society as a whole—not just the ‘economy’, but also the general form of the state
  19. and of politics. Our claim is that the Soviet system put into effect a mode of
  20. extraction of the surplus product quite different from that of capitalism. To put
  21. this point in context, some more general historical background may be useful.
  22. Consider, first, the distinction between feudal and capitalist society. Un-
  23. der feudalism, the extraction of a surplus product was plainly ‘visible’ to all.
  24. The specific forms were various, but one typical method involved the peasants
  25. working their own fields for so many days in the week, and the lord’s land for
  26. the rest. Alternatively, the peasants might have to surrender a portion of the
  27. produce of their own fields to the lord. If such a society is to reproduce itself,
  28. the direct producers must be held in some form of direct subordination or servi-
  29. tude; political and legal equality is out of the question. A religious ideology
  30. that speaks of the distinct ‘places’ allotted to individuals on this earth and of
  31. the virtues of knowing one’s proper place, and that promises a heavenly reward
  32. for those who fulfill their role in God’s earthly scheme, will also be very useful.
  33. Under capitalism, on the other hand, the extraction of the surplus product
  34. becomes ‘invisible’ in the form of the wage contract. The parties to the contract
  35. are legal equals, each bringing their property to the market and conducting a
  36. voluntary transaction. No bell rings in the factory to announce the end of the
  37. portion of the working day spent producing the equivalent of the workers’ wages,
  38. and the beginning of the production of profits for the employer. Nonetheless,
  39. the workers’ wages are substantially less than the total value of the product
  40. they generate: this is the basis of Marx’s theory of exploitation. The degree
  41. of exploitation that is realised depends on the struggle between workers and
  42. capitalists, in its various forms: over the level of wages, over the pace of pro-
  43. duction and the length of the working day, and over the changes in technology
  44. that determine how much labour time is required to produce a given quantum
  45. of wage-goods.
  46. Soviet socialism, particularly following the introduction of the first five-year
  47. plan under Stalin in the late 1920s, introduced a new and non-capitalist mode of
  48. extraction of a surplus. This is somewhat obscured by the fact that workers were
  49. still paid ruble wages, and that money continued in use as a unit of account in
  50. the planned industries, but the social content of these ‘monetary forms’ changed
  51. drastically. Under Soviet planning, the division between the necessary and
  52. surplus portions of the social product was the result of political decisions. For
  53. the most part, goods and labour were physically allocated to enterprises by
  54. the planning authorities, who would always ensure that the enterprises had
  55. enough money to ‘pay for’ the real goods allocated to them. If an enterprise
  56. made monetary ‘losses’, and therefore had to have its money balances topped
  57. up with ‘subsidies’, that was no matter. On the other hand, possession of
  58. money as such was no guarantee of being able to get hold of real goods. By
  59. the same token, the resources going into production of consumer goods were
  60. centrally allocated. Suppose the workers won higher ruble wages: by itself this
  61. would achieve nothing, since the flow of production of consumer goods was not
  62. responsive to the monetary amount of consumer spending. Higher wages would
  63. simply mean higher prices or shortages in the shops. The rate of production
  64. of a surplus was fixed when the planners allocated resources to investment in
  65. heavy industry and to the production of consumer goods respectively.
  66. In very general terms this switch to a planned system, where the the division
  67. of necessary and surplus product is the result of deliberate social decision, is
  68. entirely in line with what Marx had hoped for. Only Marx had imagined this
  69. ‘social decision’ as being radically democratic, so that the production of the
  70. surplus would have an intrinsic legitimacy. The people, having made the decision
  71. to devote so much of their combined labour to net investment and the support of
  72. non-producers, would then willingly implement their own decision. For reasons
  73. both external and internal, Soviet society at the time of the introduction of
  74. economic planning was far from democratic. How, then, could the workers be
  75. induced or compelled to implement the plan (which, although it was supposedly
  76. formulated in their interests, was certainly not of their making)?
  77. We know that the plans were, by and large, implemented. The 1930s saw
  78. the development of a heavy industrial base at unprecedented speed, a base that
  79. would be severely tested in the successful resistance to the Nazi invasion. We are
  80. also well aware of the characteristic features of the Stalin era, with its peculiar
  81. mixture of terror and forced labour on the one hand, and genuine pioneering
  82. fervour on the other. Starting from the question of how the extraction of a
  83. surplus product was possible in a planned but undemocratic system, the cult
  84. of Stalin’s personality appears not as a mere ‘aberration’, but as an integral
  85. feature of the system. Stalin: at once the inspirational leader, making up in
  86. determination and grit for what he lacked in eloquence and capable of promoting
  87. a sense of participation in a great historic endeavour, and the stern and utterly
  88. ruthless liquidator of any who failed so to participate (and many others besides).
  89. The Stalin cult, with both its populist and its terrible aspects, was central to
  90. the Soviet mode of extraction of a surplus product.
Advertisement
Add Comment
Please, Sign In to add comment
Advertisement